Revista nº 210. Eart¡ly precedents of the Country-by-Contry repotrting: implications for the analysis of corporate

 Early

precedents

of

the

Country-­‐by-­‐Country

reporting:

implications

for

the

analysis

of

corporate

power

Matti Ylönen, Doctoral student

University of Helsinki (World Politics) and Aalto University School of Business

matti.v.ylonen@gmail.com

tel. +358 40 723 11 18

Aalto University School of Business, Department of Economics

P.O. Box 21240

FI-00076 AALTO

DRAFT VERSION,

29 September 2014

Please ask permission for citation

Abstract.

In recent years, many scholars and policy makers have started to pay attention on calls for

widening the country-level publicity of corporate tax and financial information. By mapping the

history of the initiatives for country-by-country reporting, this article shows that these initiatives

have longer and more nuanced background than is commonly thought. While the current

initiatives for mandatory country-by-country reporting are of recent origin, academic authors and

the United Nations Center for Transnational Corporations proposed similar initiatives already in

the 1970s. The article offers several possible explanations on why the initiative did not gain

Ylönen 2

momentum in the earlier wave of political interest, and why policy makers have been paying

more interest this time. Moreover, I argue that the experiences of the 1970s can provide useful

insights to contemporary discussions on increasing the transparency of financial accounts. The

findings suggest that conflicts over disclosure of corporate financial information should not be

interpreted only in the context of post-financial crisis calls for greater transparency and tax

justice, but that they represent fundamental conflicts between the corporate planning system on

the one hand and states and the market economy on the other.

Keywords. Country-by-country reporting, transnational corporations, multinational companies,

intra-firm trade, economic planning

1. Introduction

“[T]here should be foreign financial reports furnished on a country-by-country basis.”

– Ralph Nader et al 1977

The advantages of transparency of financial information have contributed to much research

within the global political economy studies. Many of these contributions have focused on

banking secrecy and other forms of financial secrecy offered by tax havens to wealthy investors

and transnational corporations (e.g. Palan 2003; Sharman 2006; Palan et al 2013). Moreover,

many researchers have been interested in the concept of corporate accountability. Consequently,

one policy initiative that has gained policy level attention and academic interest in these studies

has been the idea of the “country-by-country reporting”. The term refers to a legislative proposal

under which, in its broadest version, corporations would have to report the following items by

Ylönen 3

country: the names of subsidiaries and affiliates though which the corporation operates; sales,

purchases and financial costs, broken down between third parties and intra-group transactions;

labour costs and employee numbers; pre-tax profit; several details about assets; and several

details about taxes and other payments to the government (Murphy 2009).1 Increased

transparency would allegedly enhance transnational corporations” (TNCs) compliance with tax

laws and other regulations and thus result in more just distribution of tax burdens, in addition to

other benefits (Murphy 2009).

The current policy discussions on broad country-by-country reporting began in 2003, as the

British chartered accountant Richard Murphy published a paper that outlined the idea for the new

reporting standards (see e.g. Lesage and Kaçar 2013). This proposal gained interest first amongst

civil society organizations that campaigned for economic justice and Financing for Development

issues. These calls gained increased credibility and interest amongst policy makers partly

because of the policy developments that have increased the extractive industry transparency in

the US and the EU. Consequently, several inter-governmental organizations have begun

discussing the initiative, the most notable examples being the EU and the OECD (e.g. OECD

2014, European Commission 2010). Moreover, the 2007-2009 financial crisis shaped the

political attitudes and extended the political space for demanding greater transparency of

corporate financial information. This rising societal and policy level interest has been followed

by academic attention. Country-by-country reporting has been discussed and promoted as a

viable initiative for increasing the transparency and tax compliance of TNCs on several

1 This version of country-by-country reporting will be called hereafter the “broad” version, in contrast to other

initiatives that aim to widen the current financial reporting requirements.

Ylönen 4

occasions (Lesage and Kaçar 2013; Palan et al 2013, 64; Gallhofer and Haslam 2007, 657; Urry

2014, 181).

1.1. Extractive industry campaigns created the foundation

The campaigns and initiatives demanding greater transparency for the tax and other payments of

the extractive industry companies have created grounds for country-by-country reporting

(Christians 2012, 3). For example, Wójcik notes the importance of the “initiatives calling for

improved transparency in the extractive industries, particularly with regard to payments between

corporations and host governments” behind the calls for country-by-country reporting (Wójcik

2012, 6). One early milestone in this development was achieved in year 1999, when an NGO,

Global Witness, published a report called “A Crude Awakening” that exposed the complicity of

the oil and banking industries in the plundering of state assets during Angola”s 40-year civil war.

The report claimed that the “refusal to release financial information by major multinational oil

companies aided and abetted the mismanagement and embezzlement of oil revenues by the elite

in the country”. The report then concluded that companies operating in Angola should “publish

what they pay” to the government. This led to the establishment of an NGO coalition, Publish

What You Pay (PWYP), which called companies to “publish what you pay” and governments to

“publish what you earn” as “a necessary first step towards a more accountable system for the

management of natural resource revenues”. Today, the coalition includes more than 800 NGOs

around the world (Publish What You Pay 2014).

This kind of public attention has generated political pressure on intergovernmental organizations.

The Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI) was created by the initiative of the UK

Ylönen 5

government in 2002-2003 in order to foster voluntary reporting on tax payments by the

extractive industry companies. Haufler has argued that the then UK Prime Minister Tony Blair

“shifted the focus of the EITI away from company reporting, which is the target of PWYP

activism, to reporting and membership by governments” (Haufler 2010, 65). An EITI secretariat

was set up in Oslo as an organisation that portraits itself as “a multi-stakeholder coalition of

governments, companies, investors, civil society organisations, and partner organisations” (EITI

website). The EITI requires participating governments to produce “comprehensive EITI Reports

that include full government disclosure of extractive industry revenues, and disclosure of all

material payments to government by oil, gas and mining companies”. (EITI 2013) EITI

encourages companies to support the initiative and “to promote the Standard internationally and

in countries where it operates” (ibid.). Furthermore, EITI encourages corporations to publish

more information but only on a voluntary basis. Despite its limited scope, Publish What You Pay

and many other NGOs have been partially supportive towards EITI, while continuing to criticize

its perceived flaws (Gallhofer and Haslan 2007, 649 and Haufler 2010, 66). At the same time, the

PWYP continues to campaign for disclosing information not covered by EITI, e.g. for mandatory

disclosure of the project-level payments.

Country-by-country reporting as proposed by Richard Murphy goes much further than the EITI.

The Murphy”s proposal requests a full country-level disclosure of not only taxes paid, but also of

other key financial information such as profits, names of subsidiaries and turnovers. Prevention

of corruption in a small number of industries is the major driver behind both the PWYP”s

original model and the EITI. In contrast to this, the model proposed by Murphy puts more

emphasis on enhancing tax compliance and reducing risks associated with non-transparent

corporate structures in all industries. In summary, the broad version of country-by-country

Ylönen 6

reporting would allow informed outside spectators to assess a company”s tax aggressiveness and

different kinds of risks, amongst other things, whereas the information provided in the EITI

reports do not allow this kind of analysis. Today, PWYP endorses the broad country-by-country

reporting while continuing to campaign also for its original demands.

1.2. Dodd-Frank Act and the growing international momentum

The calls for broader corporate transparency gathered more political weight in 2010, when the

US government approved the post-financial crisis Dodd-Frank legislation (Dodd-Frank Wall

Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act). Its section 1504 required extractive industry

corporations to disclose the country and project level payments for developing countries. Hong

Kong soon followed the US example. The main focus of these initiatives was on prevention of

corruption, in line with the PWYP and the EITI. However, it seems that the US legislation

created political space for requiring corporations to move parts of their financial disclosure from

the sphere of corporate secrecy to public domain, although this causality is of speculative nature.

The European Commission (EC) started consultations on country-by-country reporting in 2010

as part of the revision process of the EU”s transparency and accounting directives. The EU

concluded the reforms in 2013, and the ambition level of the amended directive was by and large

in line with the Dodd-Frank Act, with some exceptions.2 Broad country-by-country reporting

was also present in the official negotiations in the revision of the EU”s non-financial reporting

rules in 2013. Moreover, the capital requirements directive required systemically important

banks to provide increased country-level disclosure in the EU. The OECD, the IMF and the G8

2 The EU”s reporting requirements were extended to cover also some forestry companies, in

addition to the oil, gas and mining sectors included in the Dodd-Frank Act.

Ylönen 7

group have also issued statements and initiating discussions on extended country-by-country

reporting requirements (Lesage and Kaçar 2013, 262; Spencer 2014, 55-56).

So, in summary, corporate secrecy has become a contested issue in what can be considered its

most important realm, namely the financial information of the corporation. Compared to the

environmental or social performance of the corporation — two themes regularly covered in CSR

reporting — financial information is often much more closely related to the economic bottom

line of the corporation. This development has taken place in the late-1990s and especially in the

2000s, as the advocates of transparency have gradually managed to extended politically feasible

demands from the rather modest requirements of the EITI to the “hard core” of international

business. The proponents of the increased disclosure have stressed benefits related to tax

compliance; transparency of risks and other factors, but opposition has also been fierce.

Corporations and their spokespersons have maintained that increasing transparency would entail

significant extra costs (e.g. Confédération Fiscale Européenne 2013), even though some other

corporate representatives have challenged this claim (Global Witness 2013). In general, the

corporate lobbies have argued that detailed country-level reporting would reveal essential trade

secrets that are necessary for business and that wider reporting would distort competition since it

could not be applied globally (e.g. Confédeération Fiscale Européenne 2013).

In the next chapter I will argue that the recent research on this theme has not paid sufficient

attention to the historical backgrounds of these demands. I will show how increased countrylevel

disclosure was a relevant demand already in the 1970s. I will present an overview of these

ideas followed with discussion on why the initiatives were forgotten. This will enable me to

analyse what factors may have aided the initiative to gather more support today.

Ylönen 8

1.3. Research material and methodology

This article reviews and analyses the key academic publications and the UN policy documents

from the late 1960s to early 1980s that advocated different forms of country-by-country

reporting requirements for corporations. The academic discussion was documented by

identifying the most important reports, articles and books that started and carried forward the

discussions on the power of corporation in mainstream political economic discussions. I searched

this material from web databases and by other means. I screened the policy related material by

going through all material issued by the UN Center for Transnational Corporations (UNCTC)

and from reports and documents that preceded its creation. I also screened the key academic texts

that dealt with the political or planning power of the corporation, especially from the 1960s

forwards. I carried this exercise forward until same references started to reappear regularly. In

addition, this article utilized the US Senate subcommittee hearing documents as a background

material, as well as academic articles that described these policy processes (Auerbach 1962;

Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008; Rahman 1998). The documents were analyzed by close reading

(Trediga and Milne 2006).

2. Precedents of the country-by-country reporting initiative

2.1. Country-by-country reporting in academic publications

Even though the non-market aspects of large corporations have been discussed in institutional

economics for over a century (e.g. Veblen 1904, Berle and Means 1932), as well as in Marxist

Ylönen 9

studies (e.g. Baran and Sweezy 1966) the problems associated with the intra-firm profit shifting

first became a widely debated issue in the 1960s and in the 1970s. Authors such as Bhagwati

(1964) and Lall (1973) conducted empirical research on how large companies distort the prices

they use in their intra-firm trade. Galbraith (1967, 1973, 1977, 1993), Barnet and Müller (1974),

and Nader et al (1977) approached the phenomenon from more theoretical perspectives.

Galbraith proposed that the modern corporation should be analyzed as a system of planning and

administration instead of building on the idealized picture of a market system whose actors set

prices according to the market mechanism regardless of the types and sizes of corporations that

dominate the market (Galbraith 1967; Barnet & Müller 1974, see also Ylönen and Teivainen

forthcoming on these discussions).

Galbraith”s books (especially The New Industrial State, 1967) were of particular importance in

starting the debate on the power of large corporations in the US in the 1960s and 1970s.3 Several

U.S. Senate subcommittee hearings discussed “administered prices” used by monopolistic

companies in the US in years 1957-1963 and on the “role of the giant corporation” in the US

economy in years 1969-1975. Barnet and Müller”s book Global Reach (1974) gathered a

plethora of attention in the 1970s and partly expanded many of the themes originally introduced

by Galbraith, even though some critics saw deficiencies in the methodology of Barnet and

Müller that Müller then denied (see Vernon et al 1973; Keohane and Ooms 1975, 170; but see

also Müller 1974). Whereas Galbraith focused largely on how large corporations were able to

3 Galbraith”s contributions on the monopolistic nature of the US economy can be found in embryonic form also in

his earlier book American Capitalism (Galbraith 1993 [1952]). Moreover, he revisited some of the arguments he had

put forward in the New Industrial State, in The Economics and the Public Purpose (1973) and in the Age of

Uncertainty (1977).

Ylönen 10

plan and fix their prices in the economic system of the US in the 1960s and 1970s, Barnet and

Müller adopted more international approach as they analyzed the various ways how corporations

can “fiddle their accounts” and avoid taxes by intra-company transfers. Barnet and Müller saw a

situation where the

[g]lobal economic process is producing a new concentration of political power in what

are, in legal and political terms, private hands. … The principal source of their power is

their control of knowledge of three specific kinds: the technology of production and

organization—i.e., how to make, package, and transport; the technology of obtaining and

managing finance capital—i.e., how to create their own private global economy insulated

from the vicissitudes of national economies by means of shifting profits and avoiding

taxes; the technology of marketing—i.e., how to create and satisfy a demand for their

goods by diffusing a consumption ideology[.]” (Barnet and Müller 1974, 214)

Barnet and Müller also discussed how the “relative bargaining power” of corporations is

associated with the level of knowledge in the countries where they operate, and how this

discrepancy of power is particularly troubling in the “poor” countries (ibid, 193). Richer

countries were not, however, immune to the problems caused by increasing complexity of the

modern corporation and its operations. “The ease with which global corporations can conceal or

distort information vital for the management of the economy is creating the same sort of

administrative nightmare for the advanced industrial state that underdeveloped countries have

lived with for years”, Barnet and Müller predicted (1974, 256). In hindsight, this was a bold

statement, but these words did contain a significant seed of truth, as demonstrated today by the

Ylönen 11

difficulties that both the OECD and developing countries have encountered in their attempts to

ensure large corporations” tax compliance and sufficient transparency.4

One area where Barnet and Müller did not go very far, however, was policy alternatives. Even

though Barnet and Müller noted that “corporate statesmen and business reformers talk little in

public about the need for more disclosure” and recognized the need for “international regulation”

(Barnet and Müller 1974, 371), their greatest contribution in the field of alternatives was a rather

modest suggestion for an international “code of conduct” that would cover “the rights and duties

of states and global corporations”. (Barnet and Müller 1974, 372) Moreover, they argued that

Global Corporations “should become quite literally citizens of the world”, contrary to the

prevailing situation where corporations are establishing minimal and largely unenforceable limits

on their power to penetrate all national borders in the process of private global planning. (Barnet

and Müller 1974, 372)5 The policy implications of what it would mean to treat corporations as

“citizens of the world” did not, however, get much attention from Barnet and Müller.

Nader et al (1977), on the other hand, developed the analysis further by suggesting new ways to

better regulate the large corporations. They maintained that “[s]ecrecy often seems the first rule

of corporate bureaucracies, whether they are dealing with citizens, Congress, or the regulatory

4 Barnet and Müller quoted Leonard Spacek, the former chairman of Arthur Andersen & Company, who though

“that the magic words “generally accepted accounting principles” on corporate financial statements are a “fiction””

(Barnet and Müller 1974, 264) in a world where “[s]killed obfuscation is now an essential accounting tool” (ibid.,

263).

5 A conduct is often understood as a voluntary measure, but Barnet and Müller referred to a binding treaty that

would regulate the global activities of de facto global corporations.

Ylönen 12

agencies.” (ibid., 132) This poses a problem “[b]ecause knowledge is essential to democracy,

more corporate disclosure can educate, and even mobilize, communities about the hidden tolls

local companies impose—such as pollution, discrimination or underpayment of taxes” (ibid.,

136). In addition, “[m]ore corporate disclosure will also help to loosen the tight embrace between

government and business, which flourishes, like most embraces, in darkness.” (ibid.) Moreover,

the book covered common corporate critiques against transparency. The corporations often

“invoke the exigencies of the free enterprise system, which would supposedly be impaired if

additional disclosure is compelled” (ibid., 137), “joined with impassioned pleas for privacy for

the corporate “person” from the prying eyes of the public and competitors” (ibid., 138).

Consequently, trade secrecy had become “an all-purpose excuse for declining an information

request”, even though “the actual trade secrecy privilege is quite narrow” (ibid., 138).

The solutions put forward by Nader et al bore a great resemblance to the current broad countryby-

country initiative. Nader et al demanded that “consumers, taxpayers, labor, antitrust enforcers,

security holders, and state and federal authorities” should be adequately informed about the

activities of the US corporations. To achieve this, “each federally chartered corporation should

reveal its investment interest in all other companies, both foreign and domestic. All joint

ventures should be included, with identification of coparticipants, changes of ownership, and

nature and extent of the business activity. Each firm should also disclose significant long-term

contracts or debt relationships with all other companies, foreign or domestic. Existing SEC rules

require corporations to report information only for those holdings that constitute 10 per cent or

more of their aggregate assets”. (ibid., 173) Even more significantly,

Ylönen 13

The SEC”s primary effort here should be to standardize financial reporting among all large

corporations—taking into account differing economic realities in differing industries only where

absolutely necessary. “Consolidated” financial statements should represent the full operations of

the firm instead of, as at present, often only partial segments, with subsidiary or affiliated

corporations reporting as separate corporations. In multinational firms, statements should be

broken down on a “U.S.” and “all foreign” basis, in addition, there should be foreign financial

reports furnished on a country-by-country basis. The flow of foreign investment, both to and

from U.S. corporations, should be regularly disclosed, including identification of the nature of

specific new U.S. corporate investments abroad and deposits in foreign banks as well as periodic

identification of foreign loans or investment in U.S. corporations and international joint ventures.

(ibid., 176, emphasis added)

It is difficult to overstate the importance of the quotation above. While the level of detail on what

should be reported was not exactly the same as how the broad country-by-country reporting is

understood today, several of the key aspects were included.6 Most importantly, Nader et al

captured the ultimate purpose of broad country-by-country reporting, namely that the financial

reports should disclose all relevant information on corporate activities on country-by-country

basis. Moreover, he saw the initiative crucial for altering the relationships between democracy

and capitalism. However, this idea did not generate further discussion. Some authors mentioned

the book in the following decades (e.g. Strange 1997; Carruthers and Lamoreaux 2009), but

apparently nobody developed this particular aspect of the book further. To the best of knowledge

6 In addition, they also proposed other demands that dealt with corporate ownership and control, corporate relations

to the government, security holder disclosure, management income and corporate management-accountant relations

(Nader et al 1977, p. 173-176).

Ylönen 14

of this author, the commentaries on Nader”s book focused on other aspects of its contents than

the country-by-country reporting initiative. The Barnet and Müller”s book encountered similar

fate. Other scholars either criticized the book for too negative take on the corporation (Vernon

1974), or used it mostly for statistical references.

2.2. Precedents of country-by-country and segmented reporting in the UN

In addition to academic interest, states discussed initiatives for extending the financial reporting

of transnational corporations under the UN auspices in the 1970s and the 1980s. State

representatives quoted the various reports and studies documenting corporate misbehaviour (see

previous chapter), demanding concerted action against tax evasion, tax avoidance and other

questionable corporate practices. Another strand of pressure arose from the publication of a US

Senate subcommittee report in 1971 that confirmed the alleged involvement of one of the largest

multinational in destabilizing the democratic government of Salvador Allende in Chile (Rahman

1998, 595). In the July 1972 meeting of the ECOSOC, Chilean representative demanded that the

UN should commission a high-ranking expert commission to study the role of multinational

corporations (ibid. and Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008, 43-47). The ECOSOC resolution stated that

“[t]he international community has yet to formulate a positive policy and establish effective

machinery for dealing with the issues raised by the activities of these corporations” (ECOSOC

1972, 3).

The ECOSOC decided to “appoint from public and private sectors and on a broad geographical

basis a study group of eminent persons intimately acquainted with international economic, trade

and social problems and related international relations, to study the role of multinational

Ylönen 15

corporations and their impact on the process of development[.]” (ECOSOC 1972, 4). This event

marked the beginning of the UN efforts to regulate transnational corporations in the 1970s. The

ECOSOC took the initiative forward by forming the 20-member Group of Eminent Persons

(GEP) in year 1972. The group included nine members from the public sector, six from

academia, and five from public and private enterprises (Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008, 57).

The GEP finished their report in 1974 and recalled, amongst other things, that a Commission for

Transnational Corporations and an Information and Research Centre on TNCs should be

established under the ECOSOC (Rahman 1998, 599).7 A year later, in 1975, the Centre for

Transnational Corporations (UNCTC) was formed under UNCTAD, and it operated until the

year 1993 (Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008, 6). The UN member states decided also to form several subgroups

under the UNCTC. One of the groups that the UN members created was the UN group of

accounting experts (“GEISAR”) that convened in the year 1976 (Rahman 1998, 598). This

particular group is the most interesting one for the purposes of this paper.

Before discussing the GEISAR reports further, it is worth mentioning that there were some

interesting ideas in the GEP report as well. The GEP report noted that “[a]dvances in

communications technology allow many multinational corporations to pursue global strategies

which, rather than maximizing the profits or growth of individual affiliates, seek to advance the

interest of the enterprise as a whole. Lack of harmonization of policies among countries, in

7 UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs DESA prepared a background report Multinational Corporations

in World Development in the 1973 for the GEP. Many of the recommendations and analyses of the GEP group drew

heavily from this 1973 report (Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008, 59).

Ylönen 16

monetary or tax fields for example, allows multinational corporations on occasion to utilize their

transnational mobility to circumvent national policies or render them ineffective.” This

circumvention is conducted usually “by corporate planning mechanisms situated in a few

industrial countries” (UN 1974, 30), resulting in a situation where “the “invisible hand” of the

market is far from the only force guiding economic decisions” (ibid., 41).

Furthermore, according to the GEP report, corporations can thus engage in “price discrimination,

and transfer pricing”, amongst other market-distorting acts.8 (ibid., 30) The report noted that “a

policy framework which may be adequate for dealing with national corporations needs to be

modified when dealing with multinational ones” (ibid., 31), since national attempts to raise taxes

“can be negated by vertically or horizontally integrated multinational corporations through

transfer pricing and the use of tax havens” (ibid., 35). At the time, this sort of analysis on transfer

pricing and tax havens was rather unusual in its tone and contents. While the GEP report

included some policy demands,9 its major policy contribution was to pave way for the further

UN work on transnational corporations. It was especially the 1977 GEISAR report that took the

substantial accounting related issues forward.

8 It should be noted that transfer pricing as such is a necessary feature of intra-company trade in any corporation.

Transfer pricing can facilitate tax avoidance when the prices used in the intra-firm price are being distorted.

9 The report demanded that the developing countries should have larger share of the benefits from the operations of

transnational corporations (p. 29) and that capacity building and regional cooperation should be used to strengthen

the negotiating capacity of developing countries (p. 36-42). Other issues, such as sanctions and procedures in the

cases of nationalizations, were also discussed.

Ylönen 17

The aforementioned first GEISAR report noted that traditional annual reports are oriented to the

information needs of shareholders and creditors, and that there is a need for broader, improved

and more harmonized corporate reporting (UN 1977, 2). A great deal of the report described

national differences in accounting practices of different countries and on the efforts to harmonize

them. However, the report also made a detailed proposal for the items that should be furnished in

the future accounting standards. The proposal included a section on “Financial information on

members of a transnational corporation group” (ibid, 20) and another section on “Reporting on

segments of a transnational corporation” (ibid, 21). Following information was proposed for

reporting under the first category (ibid, annex p. 8):

1. List of significant subsidiaries and percentage ownership (by geographical area of operation),

justify exclusion of any such subsidiaries from consolidation. Carry excluded subsidiaries at

equity or disclose equity in the foot-notes.

2. List of associated companies and nature of relationship with parent company (by geographical

area of operation). Justify carrying such investments at other than equity and disclose equity in

the foo-notes.

3. Disclosure of identity of parent company in reports of subsidiaries.

4. Disclosure of information on the following (eliminated in consolidated statements)

(a) Intercompany sales

(b) Intercompany charges for interest, royalties, license fees, rental for use of tangible property

and other intangibles

(c) Intercompany charges for research and development, advertising, management services and

other allocated expenses

(d) Net increase (decrease) in intercompany investments

(e) Net increase (decrease) in intercompany loans

Ylönen 18

In addition, the GEISAR report demanded segment reporting for assets or net assets, revenues,

earnings, exposure to exceptional risks, principal activities in each area, new capital investments,

identifiable assets by industries, other assets, revenue and sales by industries, and one or more of

the following: profit contribution, operating profit, profit before taxes, and net profit. The

proposal thus included many of the elements of the broad country-by-country reporting as, but

with some of the key data reported on segmented level instead of country-by-country basis.

The work of the GEISAR group then continued in several subsequent reports. In the 1980

interim report the group noted that “[t]ransnational corporations should make available to the

public in the countries in which they operate clear, full and comprehensible information designed

to improve understanding of the structure, activities, and policies of the transnational corporation

as a whole. The information should include financial as well as non-financial items and should

be made available on a regular annual basis[.]” (UN 1980, Annex III) In addition, the

“information provided for the transnational corporation as a whole should be broken down by

geographical area or country, as appropriate, with regard to activities of its entities, sales,

operating results and significant new investment; and by major line of business[.]” (ibid.) These

ended up being the most important demands of the UNCTC machinery for broader corporate

reporting, alongside the suggestions put forward in the 1977 report. While the details differed,

the goals were very close to the contemporary demands: to produce public, geographically

divided information on all relevant business activities of the corporation.

Then the atmosphere changed. In the year 1984, GEISAR had switched to more cautious tone in

its analysis and its mission had been significantly narrowed. Instead of pursuing to develop new

Ylönen 19

accounting standards, the Group”s mandate had been changed “to review material from

international accountancy bodies and other interested groups” (UN 1984, 3). According to

Rahman, this reflected the increased prominence of the self-regulatory International Accounting

Standards Committee (IASC) as the main body for discussions on international accounting

regulation. In addition, the Group “considered it necessary to take account of the need of

transnational corporations to maintain business confidentiality in sensitive areas, in particular so

as not to jeopardize their competitive position” (ibid, 5). The goal was then set to “international

harmonization” as the long-term objective. (ibid, 5)

The new rhetoric resonated well with concerns that some delegations had already with the first

GEISAR report, calling it “overly ambitious”. (ibid., 5) The ambition level was significantly

reduced as a distinction was made between “general purpose” and “special purpose” reporting.

Public disclosure of “special purpose” reporting “might” be permitted only by “mutual agreement”

instead of mandatory requirement. (ibid., 5) Finally, in 1988, the UN released its conclusions on

the accounting and reporting by transnational corporations (UN 1988). Even though the

conclusions still included much of the ideas from the first GEISAR report, it had become clear

that the UN had been side-lined in the discussions on international accounting regulation.

UNCTC was dissolved in the year 1993, with some of its functions integrated to the UNCTAD.

Sagafi-Nejad et al (2008, 29) describes these events by noting that “as nation-states became more

friendly towards FDI, competing over who would give more generous incentives to attract

companies, the role of the UN shifted. The emphasis on a code of conduct, which had taken

center stage in the early years of the life of the UN Centre on Transnational Corporations, was

relegated to a secondary position and eventually oblivion[.]” After the UNCTC was dismantled,

Ylönen 20

the UNCTAD occasionally touched upon accounting issues in some of its seminars, mostly from

the angle of capacity building for the developing countries (Sagafi-Nejad et al 2008, 137). While

the UNCTC”s work on accounting continued to receive some coverage (e.g. Cobham and

McNair 2012, 44), the early proposals for country-by-country and segmented reporting were

largely forgotten.

It should be noted that the short period of the UN”s leading role in discussing international

accounting regulation was characterized by rapid decolonization especially in the 1960s.

Moreover, the conclusion of bilateral tax treaties for the elimination of double taxation emerged

from the 1960s onwards “as a salient feature of inter-State relations” (UN 2003, 3). The OECD

published its first draft model treaty for bilateral treaties in 1963 and finally the OECD Model

Double Tax Convention on Income and on Capital in 1977 (UN 2003, 3). The rules for dividing

the corporate tax incomes between states were thus developed in the same period when the UN

was discussing the rules for financial disclosure of these activities. In a way, the decolonization

accentuated many of the potential problems related to the misuse of transfer pricing that the UN

then attempted to tackle. The problems associated with tax and capital flight were thought to be

particularly developing country concerns, reflected in a strong North-South divide in many of the

debates.

3. Discussion

Corporate secrecy has become a contested issue. Contrary to a common perception, however,

there seems to be little new in the demands for greater corporate transparency. This article has

shown that scholars and the UN proposed increased country and project level disclosure for

Ylönen 21

transnational corporations already in the 1970s. The level of detail of these proposals varied, but

the perceived problems and the ways to solve them were much in line with the contemporary

concerns over corporate secrecy and its consequences. I maintain that this itself is an important

contribution to the blossoming academic interest towards transparency of the corporate financial

accounts, because the country-by-country reporting initiative has been portrayed as of a

relatively recent origin (Lesage and Kaçar 2013; 266; Urry 2014, 181). The only exception to

this seems to be Wójcik (2012), who mentions the UNCTC”s work on segmented reporting in his

paper. While the currently discussed broad version of the country-by-country reporting was

introduced only in the year 2003, the earlier attempts to widen corporate disclosure bear close

enough resemblance to broad country-by-country reporting for meriting academic attention.

It is also interesting how widely the UN reports understood the problems and threats posed by

tax havens, already in the 1970s. As explained earlier, the UN stated that the national attempts to

raise taxes “can be negated by vertically or horizontally integrated multinational corporations

through transfer pricing and the use of tax havens” (UN 1974, 35). In contrast to this, virtually all

of the academic literature on anti tax haven measures has focused on initiatives developed in the

1990s or later. The aforementioned passage suggests that researchers may want to look further

back in history to map the origins of anti tax haven policy actions. This is not the purpose of this

paper, however. I thus proceed by revisiting the analysis by Lesage and Kaçar on the factors and

threats behind the current rise of calls for country-by-country reporting, in light of the findings of

this article.

3.1. Ideas and institutional factors behind country-by-country reporting

Ylönen 22

It is worthwhile to analyse the possible reasons why demands for broader corporate transparency

failed in the 1970s, why have they fared slightly better during this era, and what could we learn

from these differences. Lesage and Kaçar (Lesage and Kaçar 2013, 277-281) have analysed the

explanations for the relative success of the current country-by-country reporting initiative, and

their analysis will provide a good starting point. Adopting a neo-Gramscian approach, they

associate the growing interest and success of the country-by-country reporting to various ideas

and institutional factors. Regarding the ideas behind country-by-country reporting, Lesage and

Kaçar find four different strands behind the “movement” for the country-by-country reporting: 1)

the tax justice CSO movement, 2) increasing interest in the tax-development nexus by the

development community, 3) the concerns about the ethics and social contributions of the

extractive industry, and 4) the fight against illicit financial flows. Even though these strands

differ in many respects, the country-by-country reporting has emerged as the policy demand

common to all four of them. Lesage and Kaçar also note how all four strands have been spurred

by developments in the international political economy over the last decade, such as the growing

awareness of the questionable aspects of financial and economic globalization (e.g. illicit

financial flows, tax havens), the UN project for the Millennium Development Goals, the UN

process on “Financing for Development”, ehigh-profile tax scandals, and the 2007-2009 global

financial crisis.

Lesage and Kaçar further note that the current movement for country-by-country reporting has

been “helped by institutional elements”. They draw attention particularly to the emerging interest

towards tax and development in the UN, OECD, EU and the Leading Group for Innovative

Mechanisms for Development, which “in turn is largely a result of the UN Financing for

Development process” (Lesage and Kaçar 2013, 278). They also note that this case shows the

Ylönen 23

importance of UN processes, “even though they are often criticized because of a lack of

immediate and substantial results”. Furthermore, Lesage and Kaçar note the importance of

IASB”s reviews of the IFRS reporting standards by the as the other institutional factor. IASB is

the successor of the aforementioned IASC and currently the only major international (selfregulatory)

body in international accounting regulation (e.g. Botzem 2012). The IASB has been

opposing country-by-country reporting, but Lesage and Kaçar still maintain that these reviews

have generated public attention for the campaign.

Comparing the Lesage and Kaçar”s analysis on the current situation to that of the 1970s, we can

see many similarities but also some major differences. First, starting with the institutional

factors, there was clearly a strong interest in the tax-development nexus by the development

community in the 1970s, at least within the UN. Second, the ethics and social contributions of

the extractive industry were discussed widely. Third, while there was no “fight against illicit

financial flows” as there is today, there certainly was a “fight” against malpractices by

transnational corporations in the developing countries, as demonstrated by the founding of the

UNCTC and e.g. by the US Senate subcommittee hearings. Most of the factors identified for the

success of the initiative were thus present also in the earlier wave. The one single factor that was

missing in the 1970s, compared to the factors presented by Lesage and Kaçar, was the tax justice

CSO movement. Lesage and Kaçar also note the significance of the 2007-2009 financial crisis as

an impetus for more transparent reporting. This factor naturally did not exist in the 1970s.10

10 Lesage and Kaçar do not include consumer awareness as a factor behind the current interest towards the countryby-

country reporting, but it is likely that this factor has also played a role in the recent developments. The power of

consumer opinion has been demonstrated e.g. in Gallup survey where a third of Britons said they are currently

boycotting a company “because it does not pay its fair share of tax” while 45 per cent stated they are considering a

Ylönen 24

Moreover, competing interests between the OECD and the southern countries characterized

discussions in the UNCTC. Today, the states have a more widely shared sense of the problems

that tax avoidance, tax evasion and other malpractices cause in both North and South.

Probably the most marked institutional difference between the international political situation of

today and the 1970s is the current heterogeneity of the global governance of economic affairs,

i.e. the institutional factors. When the UNCTC was launched in early 1970s, there was clearly a

power vacuum in the sphere of international accounting regulation. The UNCTC was able to

occupy that political space for a short span of a couple of years. Things changed rapidly,

however, as the newly formed IASC gained political prominence and, with a backing of the

major superpowers, emerged as the arena for discussions on international accounting regulation.

There was no room left for a genuinely influential policy work for the UNCTC as the major

players in international politics backed up the IASC. The IASC”s successor IASB has been at

least as reluctant towards country-by-country reporting as the IASB”s predecessor. Contrary to

the 1970s and the 1980s, however, one self-regulatory organization can no longer dominate the

discussions on international accounting regulation, not even with a mandate that greatly exceeds

that of the IASC. This gives further strength to the earlier argument that the sometimes-criticized

UN processes can be of vital importance in shaping the international policy agenda.

boycott (ComRes 2013), as well as in a public outrage on companies like Starbucks (Bergin 2012) and Stora Enso

(Ylönen and Laine 2014) that have been claimed to avoid taxes. It is also telling that a Finnish employer

organisation of the Nokia corporation decided to change their healthcare service provider after the company they

have been contracting the services from gained negative publicity from an alleged thin capitalisation related tax

avoidance structure (Helsingin sanomat 2012). This mood was not present in the 1970s.

Ylönen 25

It is also significant that while the IFRS has become the prevailing standard in the EU and

altogether in about half of the world”s nations (The American Institute of Certified Public

Accountants 2014), the standards can be adopted on a selective basis. This, together with the

precedent created by the Dodd-Frank Act, has created room for extending the country-bycountry

reporting requirements regardless of the IASB”s opinion. This kind of selective adoption

is particularly notable in the EU. There has also been a certain “institutional creep” in the OECD

and even in the IMF, as they have expanded their policy discussions to the field of accounting

regulation. So, while the IASB still champions the development of the IFRS standards, the

application of these standards has become an area of political contestations. Country-by-country

reporting initiative is one significant example of these contestations. Moreover, the expertisebased

civil society organizations such as the Tax Justice Network, together with a more diverse

financial media than in the 1970s, also act as watchdogs that pressure the international

organizations and politicians for more ambitious targets in promoting transparency.

In summary, the project for extending country-by-country and segmented reporting in the 1970s

was institutionally conducted in a sort of winner-takes-it-all situation. The UN made a major

headway with the work conducted in the UNCTC and its GEISAR group, but their glory faded as

the balance of power shifted in favour of the IASC. This development was accentuated by the

lack of additional forces (civil society, media, other international organizations) that would have

been able to keep up the pressure. In comparison, today”s political situation is much more

diverse with regards to both ideas and institutions. This allows CSOs, international

organizations, politicians and even investors to gain small but repeated political victories in

progressing the country-by-country reporting in spite of the powerful resistance from the IASB

and elsewhere. Moreover, various EU bodies have expressed their support for the initiative.

Ylönen 26

Furthermore, Lesage and Kaçar note that there are many obstacles that can still stop the progress

of the country-by-country reporting. One obstacle is the power of the business lobbies that

oppose wider disclosure. Second obstacle is the tendency to restrict the reporting to the

extractive industries. The IASB has agreed to open up the discussion on the narrower demands of

the Publish What You Pay Coalition, but not on the full country-by-country reporting. As a result

of these obstacles, Lesage and Kaçar maintain that “there is a danger that, under pressure from

business interests, Western governments will limit themselves to a minimalist approach in which

the extractive industry is singled out as a scapegoat, while leaving the rest of big business off the

hook” (Lesage and Kaçar 2013. 279). This could result in disempowering the movement, Lesage

and Kaçar argue.

The example of the development of broader disclosure requirements in the UNCTC shows how

difficult it is to create a lasting political initiative if its success depends on the political will and

resources of one single international organization under constant threat of losing its legitimacy in

the eyes of the prevailing powers. The results from the loss of legitimacy and power of the

UNCTC, coupled with the loss of interest of the US Senate in researching the political power of

the corporation, and with the ideological turn of the end-1970s, were devastating in such an

extent that the substantial inputs proposed by the UNCTC and the scholars of the time seem to

have been forgotten by the academia, policy makers and the civil society. On the other hand,

compared to the 1970s, there is today a much wider consensus between northern and southern

countries on the issues and problems at stake. Therefore, playing down the proposed initiatives is

and will likely be more difficult for their opponents that in the earlier decades.

Ylönen 27

3.2. Contestations on corporate transparency in the larger framework of capitalism

This article has shown how different forms of country-by-country reporting were discussed

already in the 1970s. In other words, transparency of corporate financial information was a

contested issue much before the financial crisis, massive growth of tax haven related business,

and the immaterial economy that makes it so easy for corporations to exploit the commercialized

sovereignty of tax havens. Could it then be that the contestations over corporate financial

information represent something bigger that just a partly coincidentally born initiative that has

been favoured by a particular set of institutional and idea related factors? The examples from the

1970s seem to suggest that contestations over financial transparency should indeed be interpreted

also in the wider context of democracy and capitalism. I will next turn to discuss some concepts

developed by John Kenneth Galbraith in order to analyze these questions further. I will argue

that it is likely that the level of transparency of corporate financial information is a source of

fundamental and persisting conflicts in corporate-state relations, as well as between the planning

system utilized by large transnational corporations and the more competitive market system

typically associated with smaller companies (Galbraith 1967).

According to Galbraith, “the great corporation maximizes not pecuniary return but the whole

complex of organizational interests of which pecuniary return is only one part, and that it goes on

to ensure that the goals of the larger community and state will be sympathetic to its own” (1967,

617-618). Corporate planning is a consequence of the need to balance between these diverging

interests (Galbraith 1967, 646). And, “as viewed by the firm, elimination of a market converts an

external negotiation and hence a partially or wholly uncontrollable decision to a matter for purely

internal decision” (ibid. 652). Information is a key prerequisite for successful planning. “There

Ylönen 28

must be men whose knowledge allows them to foresee need and to ensure a supply of labor,

materials and other production requirements; those who have the knowledge to plan price

strategies and see that customers are suitably persuaded to buy at these prices; those who, at

higher levels of technology, are so informed that they can work effectively with the state to see

that it is suitably guided; and those who can organize the flow of information that the above tasks

and many others require” (ibid., 685). This planning economy runs parallel to the market

economy, where companies have to take prices as they exist in the market or, in case of

subcontractors, as defined by the large corporations who negotiate the contracts.

I maintain that the level of financial transparency is a major factor in determining where the

competitive markets end and the planning economy begins, even more so than in the

comparatively closed US economic context that Galbraith analyzed in the 1960s and the 1970s.

As Barnet and Müller noted already in the 1970s, the international dimension greatly expands the

possibilities for corporations to plan their prices. However, the globalization of business has led

to a situation where the control of information carries much more importance in determining how

well the corporation can or cannot plan where to show its profits and what prices to utilize. There

are three factors behind this increase in the importance of information as a factor of the planning

power of larger corporations.

First, the globalization of business has led to an increasing number of situations where tax

authorities do not automatically possess the information needed to validate the tax information

they have obtained from a company. Even if authorities can request the company to provide

whatever accounts they need to assess the tax payments, they need substantial resources to

conduct these requests. Moreover, by requesting information from the company, the authorities

Ylönen 29

in effect indicate to a company that they are monitoring it. Therefore, tax authorities have to rely

at least partially on publicly available data in their risk analyses and screenings of companies that

should to be audited. The more information that is publicly available to the authorities, the

greater opportunities they have for conducting and monitoring corporate tax issues. In a situation

where the level of national and aggregated level availability of financial accounts has stayed

more or less stable and business has globalized, the actual relative level of publicity has greatly

declined. This stems from the fact that the more complex and multinational a company becomes;

more effort is consequently needed to understand its internal workings. This has increased the

planning power of corporations over their internal prices and decreased the planning power of

states to design and implement their tax systems.

Second, the global, brand-driven corporations are in greater danger to suffer from negative

publicity than in the earlier decades. The greater the level of publicity of financial accounts, the

greater probability there is that aggressive tax planning arrangements will create negative

publicity for the corporation. Transparency of country-level financial information acts thus as a

catalyst that can urge corporations to restrict their tax planning, shifting the balance of planning

power more to states” favour and helping to maintain the sphere of competitive market economy.

And third, the extent of country-level financial transparency can affect the division line between

the planning economy and market economy. More financial information gives better tools for

competitors and subcontractors to evaluate the profitability of particular business units or

activities, thus levelling the playing field between different kinds of market actors. The less large

corporations can engage in distortive corporate planning, the more space there is for their smaller

competitors and subcontractors.

Ylönen 30

Taking these viewpoints into account, the country-level transparency of corporate financial

information should be seen as a much larger issue than a matter of securing tax revenues or

exposing financial risks that current reporting requirements do not reveal. In the contemporary

economy, the level of financial transparency can have significant impacts over where the

planning economy starts and market economy begins. Moreover, transparency requirements

affect also the capacity of states to plan their national economies, in contrast with corporations”

capacities to plan their internal transactions and profit sharing. It should therefore come as no

surprise that the demands for broader country-by-country or segmented level transparency were

so prominently present in the debates on the corporate planning powers of the 1970s, even

though the world economy was much less globalized than today. The initiative should also be

understood as a key one in attempts to make the structures and actors of global capitalism more

democratically accountable.

The large corporations and their spokesmen are most likely well aware of the threats that the

broad country-by-country reporting poses to their capacities to plan their prices, exert power over

smaller competitors, and to decide how much information they want to disclose on particular

branches of their businesses. In addition to the strong opposition the corporate front groups have

expressed toward extending the country-level transparency, this attitude is also manifest in

mushrooming voluntary “tax footprint” reports that have been published in recent years by many

companies, from the PWC”s Total Tax Contribution to the individual reports of companies such

as Vodafone and others. Typically, these reports list a rather arbitrary set of taxes and other

“contributions” that the corporation pays to some states where it operates, without any mentions

on the corporation”s tax planning, financial risks or other factors that the broad country-bycountry

reporting would reveal. In other words, the corporations take very seriously the

Ylönen 31

perceived threats of lowering the current level of corporate secrecy and thus indirectly their

planning powers.

4. Concluding remarks

In summary, this article has contributed to the body of political economy literature on corporate

transparency and power in three particular respects. First, the article has provided new

information and analysis on the early history of the country-by-country reporting initiative, thus

contributing to and in parts challenging some earlier accounts on this topic. Second, as a “byproduct”,

the text has hinted that we should look further back in history in order to understand the

history of the initiatives against tax havens. Third, the article has suggested that a framework of

“corporate planning” could be a fruitful framework in order to understand some of the tax and

transparency related conflicts between states and large corporations on the one hand, and large

corporations and the market economy on the other.

The second and third contributions are also the most interesting ones for further research. The

UN processes and early national political contestations over tax haven use would merit further

exploration. Moreover, the framework of “corporate planning” and its relationship to profit

shifting and tax haven use could also create interesting avenues for research on corporate power.

The role of corporate financial information is one area in the wider realm of corporate planning

that uses profit shifting as its tool. Some suggestions for widening this analysis are presented in

Ylönen and Teivainen forthcoming. And finally, on limitations of this study: there might be some

further strands of early studies that discuss country-by-country reporting that this author has not

Ylönen 32

managed to find. However, a great effort has been made to minimize this potential caveat in

collecting and identifying the research material.

References

Auerbach, Carl A. 1962. “Administered Prices and the Concentration of Economic Power.”

Minnesota Law Review 47: 139.

Baran, Paul M. and Paul A. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly Capital: an Essay on the American

Economic and Social Order. Monthly Review Press. New York.

Barnet, Richard J., and Ronald E. Müller. 1974. Global Reach: The Power of the Multinational

Corporations. Simon and Schuster.

Bergin, Tom. 2012. “Special Report: How Starbucks Avoids UK Taxes.” Reuters, October 15.

Berle, Adolf Augustus, and Gardiner Coit Means. 1934. The Modern Corporation and Private

Property. Macmillan.

Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1964. “On the Underinvoicing of Imports1.” Bulletin of the Oxford

University Institute of Economics & Statistics 27 (4): 389–97. doi:10.1111/j.1468-

0084.1964.mp27004007.x.

Botzem 2012. The politics of accounting regulation. Edward Elgar Publishing. Cheltenham.

Carruthers, Bruce G, and Naomi Lamoreaux. 2009. Regulatory Races: The Effects of

Jurisdictional Competition on Regulatory Standards. Working paper, Department of

Sociology, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.

Christians, Allison. 2012. Tax Activists and the Global Movement for Development Through

Transparency. SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2029055. Rochester, NY: Social Science

Research Network. http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2029055.

Ylönen 33

Cobham, Alex and David McNair. 2012. The Role of Rich Countries in Development : The Case

for Reforms. Handbook of accounting and development.

ComRes 2013. Christian Aid, Tax Avoidance Survey.

http://www.comres.co.uk/polls/Christian_Aid_Tax_Avoidance_Feb_2013.pdf.

Confederation Fiscale Europeenne. 2013. Opinion Statement FC 6/2013 of the CFE on countryby-

country reporting of tax information by large companies. Prepared by the CFE Fiscal

Committee. Submitted to the European Institutions in December 2013.

http://www.nob.net/system/files/CFE+Opinion+Statement+on+country+by+country+rep

orting+of+tax+information.pdf.

ECOSOC 1972. Resolutions. Supplement No. 1.Economic and Social Council. Official Records.

Fifty-third session. 3-28 July 1972. United Nations.

EITI 2013. EITI Factsheet 2013. Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative.

European Commission. 2010. Public consultation on country-by-country reporting by

multinational companies. Directorate General for Internal Market and Services. 22

December 2010.

Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1967. The New Industrial State. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

———.. 1973. Economics and the Public Purpose. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

———. 1977. The Age of Uncertainty. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

———. 1993. American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. New edition. New

Brunswick, N.J., U.S.A: Transaction Publishers.

Gallhofer, Sonja, and Jim Haslam. 2007. “Exploring Social, Political and Economic Dimensions

of Accounting in the Global Context: The International Accounting Standards Board and

Accounting Disaggregation.” Socio-Economic Review 5 (4): 633–64.

Ylönen 34

Global Witness. 2013. Norway”s national oil company Statoil withholds support from US antitransparency

lawsuit. 8th February 2013. http://www.globalwitness.org/library/norway”snational-

oil-company-statoil-withholds-support-us-anti-transparency-lawsuit

Haufler, Virginia. 2010. “Disclosure as Governance: The Extractive Industries Transparency

Initiative and Resource Management in the Developing World.” Global Environmental

Politics 10 (3): 53–73.

Helsingin Sanomat. 2012. “3T: Nokia Vaihtaa Mehiläisen Terveystaloon.” Helsingin sanomat.

6.9.2012.

Keohane, Robert O., and Van Doorn Ooms. 1975. “The Multinational Firm and International

Regulation.” International Organization 29 (1): 169–209.

Lall, Sanjaya. 1973. “Transfer-Pricing by Multinational Manufacturing Firms1.” Oxford Bulletin

of Economics and Statistics 35 (3): 173–95. doi:10.1111/j.1468-

0084.1973.mp35003001.x.

Lesage, Dries, and Yusuf Kaçar. 2013. “Tax Justice through Country-by-Country Reporting: An

Analysis of the Idea”s Political Journey.” In Tax Justice and the Political Economy of

Global Capitalism, 1945 to the Present, 262–82. Berghahn Books.

Müller, Ronald. 1973. “Poverty Is the Product.” Foreign Policy, no. 13: 71.

doi:10.2307/1147769.

Murphy, Richard. 2009. “Country-by-Country Reporting. Holding Multinational Corporations to

Account Wherever They Are”. Financial Integrity and Transparency Coalition.

Nader, Ralph, Mark J. Green, and Joel Seligman. 1977. Taming the Giant Corporation. Norton.

OECD. 2014. Discussion Draft on Transfer Pricing Documentation and CbC Reporting. Public

Consultation. 30 January 2014. OECD. Paris.

Ylönen 35

Palan, Ronen. 2003. The Offshore World: Sovereign Markets, Virtual Places, and Nomad

Millionaires. Cornell University Press. New York.

Palan, Ronen, Richard Murphy, and Christian Chavagneux. 2013. Tax Havens: How

Globalization Really Works. Cornell University Press.

Publish What You Pay. 2014. About us. Www-page. http://www.publishwhatyoupay.org/about.

Accessed 7 August 2014.

Rahman, Sheikh F. 1998. “International Accounting Regulation by the United Nations: A Power

Perspective.” Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal 11 (5): 593–623.

doi:10.1108/09513579810239864.

Sagafi-Nejad, Tagi, John H Dunning, and Howard V Perlmutter. 2008. The UN and

Transnational Corporations: From Code of Conduct to Global Compact. Bloomington:

Indiana University Press.

Sharman, Jason Campbell. 2006. Havens in a Storm: The Struggle for Global Tax Regulation.

Cornell University Press.

Spencer, David, 2014. “Transfer Pricing: Formulary Apportionment is not a Panacea, Part 1”.

International Taxation, April 2014.

Strange, Susan. 1997. Casino Capitalism. Manchester; New York: Manchester University Press.

The American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 2014. IFRS FAQ. www-site.

http://www.ifrs.com/ifrs_faqs.html#q3

Tregidga, H. and Milne, M.J. 2006. “From sustainable management to sustainable development:

a longitudinal analysis of a leading New Zealand environmental reporter”, Business

Strategy and the Environment, Vol. 15, pp. 219-241.

UN 1974. The impact of multinational corporations on development and on international

relations. United nations publication E/5500/Rev.1/St/Esa/6. United nations, New York.

Ylönen 36

UN 1977. International standards of accounting and reporting for transnational corporations.

United nations publication St/Ctc/5. United Nations Center for Transnational

Corporations. United Nations, New York.

UN 1980. Comprehensive information system: International standards of accounting and

reporting. Interim report of the Ad Hoc Intergovernmental Working Group of Experts in

International Standards of Accounting and Reporting. Economic and Social Council,

Commission on Transnational Corporations, Sixth session, Agenda item 6b. 12 March

1980. United Nations, New York.

UN 1984. International Standards of Accounting and Reporting Report of the ad hoc

intergovernmental group of experts on international standards of accounting and

reporting. United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations. E/C.10/1982/8/Rev.1.

United Nations, New York.

UN 1988. Report of the Intergovernmental Working Group of Experts on International

Standards of Accounting and Reporting in its sixth session. International standards of

accounting and reporting. Economic and social council. Commission on transnational

corporations. Fourteenth session. 6-15 April 1988. Item 6 of the provisional agenda.

E/C.10/1988/6. United Nations, New York.

UN 2003. Manual for the negotiation of bilateral tax treaties between developed and developing

countries. Economic and Social Affairs. United Nations, New York.

Urry, John. 2014. Offshoring. 1 edition. Polity.

Veblen, Thorsten. 1904. The Theory of Business Enterprise. C. Scribner”s Sons. New York.

Vernon, Raymond, Richard J. Barnet, and Ronald Muller. 1974. “An Exchange on

Multinationals.” Foreign Policy, no. 15: 83. doi:10.2307/1147930.

Ylönen 37

Wojcik, Dariusz. 2012. Shining Light on Globalization: The Political Economy of Country-by-

Country Reporting. SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2163449. Rochester, NY: Social Science

Research Network. http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2163449.

Ylönen, Matti and Teivo Teivainen. Forthcoming. Political Implications of Intra-Firm Trade:

Transnational Corporations as Economic Planners.